Scalable versus Productive Technologies UPDATED DRAFT!!!
(with Mons Chan, Guangbin Hong, Joachim Hubmer, and S. Salgado)Why Are the Wealthiest So Wealthy? New Longitudinal Empirical Evidence and Implications for Theories of Wealth Inequality (revision requested by Econometrica)
(with Joachim Hubmer, E. Halvorsen, and S. Salgado)Working paper CRNY SLIDES Bibtex file
(An earlier version of this paper was circulated under the title “Income Differences and Health Care Expenditures over the Life Cycle.”)Anatomy of Lifetime Earnings Inequality: Heterogeneity in Job Ladder Risk vs Human Capital, Journal of Political Economy: Macroeconomics, 2023
(with J. Song and F. Karahan)Published version NBER EF&G SLIDES 2021 Draft Data and Code Bibtex file
Media Coverage and Blogs: OTE Blog #1 OTE Blog #2 OTE Blog #3 Bloomberg
Dissecting Idiosyncratic Income Risk, Journal of European Economic Association, 2023
(with E. Halvorsen, H. Holter and K. Storesltetten)Published version 2020 Draft SLIDES Data and Code JEEA Teaching Material
Earnings Dynamics and Its Intergenerational Transmission: Evidence from Norway, Quantitative Economics, 2022.
(with E. Halvorsen and S. Salgado)What Do Data on Millions of U.S. Workers Say About Lifecycle Labor Income Risk?, Econometrica, 2021
(with F. Guvenen, F. Karahan, and J. Song)Heterogeneous Scarring Effects of Full-Year Nonemployment, American Economic Review P&P, 2017
(with F. Guvenen, F. Karahan and J. Song)The Nature of Countercyclical Income Risk , Journal of Political Economy, 2014
(with F. Guvenen and J. Song)Taxation of Human Capital and Wage Inequality: A Cross-Country Analysis, Review of Economic Studies, 2014
(with F. Guvenen and B. Kuruscu)On the Persistence of Income Shocks over the Life Cycle: Evidence, Theory, and Implications, Review of Economic Dynamics, 2013
(with F. Karahan)High Risk Workers and High Risk Firms SED Slides
(with Marlène Koffi, Sergio Salgado, and Marco Weißler )Labor Market Risk and Racial Disparities in Lifetime Earnings: The Roles of Worker and Firm Heterogeneity
(with V. Gregory, F. Leenders, and D. Wiczer )Revisiting Gibrat’s Legacy: An Empirical Investigation of Nonlinear Firm Dynamics
(with B. Pugsley and S. Salgado)”The Life-Cycle Dynamics of Wealth Mobility” by Audoly, McGee, Ocampo, and Paz-Pardo
”Why Are Returns to Private Business Wealth So Dispersed?” by Boar, Gorea, and Midrigan
”Cyclical Earnings, Career and Employment Transitions” by Carrillo-Tudela, Visschers, and Wiczer
”Firm Heterogeneity in Skill Returns” by Böhm, Esmkhani, and Gallipoli
“Income and Wealth Inequality in America,1949-2016” by Kuhn, Schularick, and Steins
A Rich Set of Moments on Labor Income Dynamics from the US SSA's Master Earnings File
The empirical moments on labor income dynamics we documented in my papers using the SSA's Master Earnings file.
There are more than 10,000 moments reported in these files ranging from very simple average life-cycle earnings profiles to higher-order moments of long-term earnings growth by year, age and past income. These moments are intended to be used by researchers in their calibration exercises.
Moments documented in "What Do Data on Millions of U.S. Workers Say About Lifecycle Labor Income Risk?", Econometrica 2021 (with F. Guvenen, F. Karahan, and J. Song).
Moments documented in "The Nature of Countercyclical Income Risk", Journal of Political Economy 2014 (with F. Guvenen and J. Song).
Very efficient and flexible global optimization algorithm.
This algorithm is evolved out of Fatih Guvenen's joint projects with me and Tony Smith, Fatih Karahan, Tatjana Kleineberg, and Antoine Arnaud.
You can read the description of this algorithm in this paper and find its applications in my papers here, here and there.
You can find my version on GitHub.
Great care was taken to make it as compliant with Fortran 90 as possible, but there may be a couple of invocations to Fortran 95 intrinsics.
Parallel performance. Here is an example of the scaling performance of TikTak on an SMM estimation problem with 1200+ moments and 7 parameters (taken from Guvenen, Karahan, Ozkan, Song (2021, specification in Table IV, column 2).
This figure shows the completion time of TikTak against the number of cores used in parallel, with the condition that the objective attained is always within 1% of the single-core value. The log-log plot is almost linear from 1 to 32 cores, with a slope of -0.976 showing almost linear scaling. Doubling the number of cores from 32 to 64 yields a final objective value that exceeds the 1% threshold.
The estimation required about N=1000 restarts (or local optimizations) in the global stage, so these results suggest a heuristic: #core ≤ sqrt(N) (sqrt(1000) ≈ 32), for the number of cores that can be used in parallel with linear scaling and no performance degradation. (Although we found that in this example, using 50 cores still delivered linear scaling without slowdown, so further experimentation is recommended).
Prepared for a special issue of the Quantitative Economics edited by F. Guvenen, L. Pistaferri and G. Violante.
Part of the Global Income Dynamics Project, which aims to produce a harmonized cross-country database containing detailed and relevant statistics on individual- and householdlevel wages, earnings, and related labor market measures.
The STATA code used to produce the harmonized statistics in all countries is prepared by S. Salgado and myself. Please email us to gain access to the code. Please cite the below paper if you use your code in your project.
Here is our paper part of this project:
Earnings Dynamics and Its Intergenerational Transmission: Evidence from Norway, Quantitative Ecoomics, 2022.
(with E. Halvorsen and S. Salgado )
Published version Replication files 2020 Draft - Longer version
Abstract: Using administrative data from Norway, we first present stylized facts on labor earnings dynamics between 1993 and 2017 and its heterogeneity across narrow population groups. We then investigate the parents' role in children's income dynamics—the intergenerational transmission of income dynamics. We find that children of high-income, high-wealth fathers enjoy steeper income growth over the life cycle and face more volatile but more positively skewed income changes, suggesting that they are more likely to pursue high-return, high-risk careers. Children of poorer fathers also face more volatile incomes, but theirs grow more gradually and are more left skewed. Furthermore, the income dynamics of fathers and children are strongly correlated. In particular, children of fathers with steeper life-cycle income growth, more volatile incomes, or higher downside risk also have income streams of similar properties. We also confirm that fathers' significant role in workers' income dynamics is not simply spurious because of omitted variables, such as workers' own permanent income. These findings shed new light on the determinants of intergenerational mobility.